Games and Tribes

#feedwhytip {
background-image:url(http://c4.nrostatic.com/images/feed_tooltip_black_arrow.gif);
}
#div_ad_holder {
margin-top: 12px;
margin-bottom: 12px;
}
#nav_star {
margin-top: -13px;
margin-left: -1px;
}

<!--

--><!--

--><!--

--><!-- 989 reasons

--><!--

(No thanks. Take me to NRO.)

-->


<!---->


<!-- -->
<!-- -->



<!--

Get FREE NRO Newsletters

-->

Log In  |  Register

Follow Us

 
 

April 8 Issue 

Subscribe to NR 

Renew 



April 8 Issue  |  Subscribe  |  Renew






Close

Games and Tribes

Liberals assume wealth is static; conservatives know it’s the result of a dynamic process.

By Kevin D. Williamson

Archive
Latest

RSS

Send

Text

 

Kevin D. Williamson 

There’s a joke among psychology researchers: We know almost nothing about human psychology, but we know everything about the psychology of Harvard psychology undergrads — because they’re the ones who serve as the subjects of influential studies. It is likely that the same thing holds true of experimental economics.

Economists like to study human behavior through games, two of the most common being the Dictator Game and the Ultimatum Game. Dictator Game is simple: Player A is given a sum of money to divide any way he likes with Player B. Player B has no say in the transaction. (Dictator Game is not formally a game, since outcomes are not determined by any interaction among players.) Ultimatum Game is like Dictator Game, but with an important variable: Player B has veto power. Player A proposes a split, and Player B has the power to accept it, in which case both parties get something, or reject it, in which case neither party gets anything.

Advertisement

Ultimatum Game is often used to show that people in the real world are not representatives of the purely utility-maximizing species Homo economicus. If they were, the game would play out like this: Given $100 to divide, Player A would propose a split of $99 for himself and $1 for Player B, and Player B would accept it every time — and, perhaps more important, Player A would know that Player B would accept it every time. Player B is better off with $1 than with nothing, so Player A is confident that he can keep most of the prize for himself in exchange for offering the minimum benefit to Player B. In the real world, it does not work that way. Most people in the B position will reject a split of less than 60/30, and people in the Player A position tend to offer splits around 50/50. When asked why, players remark that very uneven splits just seem “unfair.”

At least, certain kinds of players do that — namely, players from developed Western societies. Those with very different cultural backgrounds behave in ways that would surprise most Americans, as the social scientist Duncan J. Watts documents in his very enjoyable book Everything Is Obvious Once You Know the Answer. For example, A players from cultures that have strong traditions of reciprocal gift-giving may make hyper-generous offers, presumably because such an open-handed gesture would oblige the recipient in some meaningful way. Interestingly, B players with similar backgrounds will reject hyper-generous offers more often than Westerners typically would, presumably because they do not wish to take on the unspecified obligation that accepting such a gift would entail. Conversely, players from cultures with very little tradition of cooperation between people who are not related tend to behave more like Homo economicus: Offering and expecting the minimum.

The ability to negotiate the two kinds of games in a way that maximizes one’s own interests — parsimonious in the Dictator Game, just generous enough in the Ultimatum Game — is sometimes used as a measure of what researchers call “Machiavellian intelligence,” the ability to navigate social groups profitably.

As Watts points out, players in these kinds of games, regardless of their cultural background, have a hard time explaining why they have the particular sets of preferences they have: They have internalized their rules of the game without ever quite being conscious of them.

Liberals and conservatives do not agree on much, but we often agree on this: The people in the opposite camp often seem like they come from another country, from another society and culture altogether. Conservatives in New York City or on the campus of Bryn Mawr College may feel like they have been parachuted into an alien and possibly hostile environment, and no doubt liberals feel like that when their magazine editors send them on National Review cruises. It may be the case that Red America and Blue America really are separate societies, at least on some micro-cultural level.

Such studies as have been done on the relationship between the Ultimatum Game and political preferences have been inconclusive, which is disappointing. There are a few tantalizing little bits: High levels of Machiavellian intelligence have been associated with “right-wing” economic preferences (which of course are more accurately known as “liberal” economic preferences outside our own perversely up-is-down political discourse), while progressive types have been found to be relatively generous in the Dictator Game but not in the Ultimatum Game, which comports nicely with the conservative hunch that liberals are most generous when the other guy doesn’t really have any say in the matter. (That’s only the case in one study I’ve come across; it would be interesting to see this explored more deeply.)

Text

 

Listen to the Audio Version

').show();
AudioPlayer.embed("outloudaudio", { soundFile: data.audio, titles: "Games and Tribes" });
}
});

Subscriptions
NR / Print
NR / Digital

Gift Subscriptions
NR / Print
NR / Digital

NRO Articles  |  
Article RSS  |  
Author Directory


');

//Post Form Data
subscribe(email);
var om = setTimeout(function() {
//Display Thank You
jQuery('#newsmax-block-bottom').html('

We have just sent you a confirmation e-mail. Thank you for registering with NRO!

');
}, 400);
});

// Sign Up Form Submission Function
function subscribe(email) {
var url = "http://www.newsmax.com/CmsPages/newsmax/Handlers/AlterianSubscribe.ashx?email=" + email.toString();
url = encodeURI(url);
if (jQuery.browser.msie window.XDomainRequest) {
// Use Microsoft XDR
var xdr = new XDomainRequest();
xdr.open("get", url);
xdr.onload = function() {
// XDomainRequest doesn't provide responseXml, so if you need it:
var dom = new ActiveXObject("Microsoft.XMLDOM");
dom.async = false;
dom.loadXML(xdr.responseText);
}
xdr.send();
}
else {
jQuery.post(url);//, { func: "something" }, function(data) { alert(data); },"text");
}
}
});


'; } else if (google_ads.length 1) { ad_unit2 += ''; } } document.getElementById("ad_unit2").innerHTML += ad_unit2; google_adnum += google_ads.length; return; } google_ad_client = "ca-pub-7596656896688386"; google_ad_output = 'js'; google_max_num_ads = '6'; google_feedback = "on"; google_ad_type = "text"; google_adtest = "off"; google_image_size = '300x250'; google_skip = '6'; google_ad_region = 'test';








‘We’re Not Here to Be Popular’ — The NRA’s Strategy: . . .

Why Not Assisted Suicide for the Grieving?: British novelist Julian . . .

White House Withdraws Halligan Nomination: Politico reports on the demise . . .

Color Lines and Boxes: The cover story in the spring . . .

Tackling the Geographical Dispersion of Low-Income High-Achievers: Caroline Hoxby and . . .

Joe Biden’s Pricey Hotel Stay in London: When the president . . .

Germany vs. Russia in Cyprus: It’s Germany versus Russia again. . . .



Print



Digital



iOS



Android

<!--


Android

-->

 

Quantcast


Quantcast

Open bundled references in tabs:

Leave a Reply